In May, the personal consumption expenditures deflator finally popped above the 2% target of the Federal Open Market Committee — both the annualized increase from April and compared to May 2017.
Popularly called “inflation,” it conjures images that prices generally rose 2% or that the increase was due to monetary causes (primarily federal funds rate and Fed’s balance sheet) controlled by the FOMC.
Is that true? Not really.
The PCE deflator is a weighted average of product price changes. The U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis publishes over 300 deflators from high-level aggregates to more specific product types. The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics publishes hundreds more.
Product prices vary widely.
Just at a high-level, gasoline and other energy goods grew almost five times as fast as the next category, financial services and insurance.
Clearly, prices vary widely. But, deflators are weighted by purchases. Housing and utilities purchases are 7.2 times the size of gasoline and other energy goods and 18.1% of all PCE. So, housing and utilities made the top contribution to the PCE deflator in May.
If the goal is to turn off the water faucet, it doesn’t help to turn off a light switch.
The point of the 2% target as a policy guide is that the price change is assumed to be due to monetary causes and controllable by the FOMC.
But, that control varies:
• Housing has a direct link in the FOMC’s purchases of agency mortgage-backed securities. Housing loans are influenced by the FOMC to the extent they are linked to the federal funds rate. But, if the loan funds come from global sources, then it is less.
• Financial services and insurance has direct links via both the FOMC and the Federal Reserve’s regulatory powers.
• Gasoline and health care depend on specific decisions beyond the FOMC.
• Central banks have influence through foreign exchange rates.
• Central banks have no influence on technology, online shopping, or government, tax, subsidy, trade, and regulatory policies.
The less influence the FOMC has, the more reason to rethink monetary policy.
Shoppers have been buying more durables as prices fall since 1995 – thanks to the global tech and trade transformation.
This downward slope holds for both individual products and across product types over time. Below is the “across” pattern in the past twelve months of data.
Other durable goods are mostly jewelry, educational books, and medical equipment. These luxuries and necessities aren’t as price-sensitive.
What matters
• Price increases aren’t widespread or mostly monetary-caused
• Higher prices tend to cut purchases – directly hurting real (price-level-adjusted) gross domestic product. This insight is hidden when nominal GDP is targeted.
• Due to stark differences in services v. goods, discretionary v. nondiscretionary, and location, any FOMC action will distort and most hurt those people least able to escape.
Brian Barnier is head of data analytics at ValueBridge Advisors (U.S.) and Burnt Oak Capital (UK) with a focus on managing risk in investment and operating companies. He is co-founder of www.feddashboard.com for busting economic and market myths.